Referendums in the United Kingdom - Constitution Committee Contents


Examination of Witnesses (Questions 156-174)

Professor Michael Marsh and Dr Helena Catt

3 FEBRUARY 2010

  Q156  Chairman: Dr Catt and Professor Marsh, can I welcome you to the Committee and thank you very much indeed for joining us? We are being sound recorded and so I will ask you, if I may, to formally identify yourselves for the record; and if you wish to make a brief opening statement, please feel free to do so. You are under no obligation to do so.

Dr Catt: I am Dr Helena Catt. Most recently I was the Chief Electoral Commissioner in New Zealand; prior to that I was an Associate Professor in Politics at the University of Auckland. I will not be making a brief statement, I will just go straight to questions.

  Professor Marsh: My name is Michael Marsh: I am Professor of Comparative Political Behaviour at Trinity College Dublin; and I will not be making an opening statement. Again, I would move to your questions rather than my views.

  Q157  Chairman: Thank you both very much. Can I kick off by asking what you each think about the strengths and the weaknesses of referendum as an instrument of political activity?

  Dr Catt: I think there is only one possible strength and that is that in some instances it can legitimise a question about how democracy works. So to answer your last question, I think the only time they are useful is on a question about democracy, for instance the electoral system or devolution. The negatives—I think there are many. I think that they polarise issues, they isolate one issue and divorce it from the relating issues. They are very expensive to do properly and if you are not going to spend the money on it, it is not worth doing it. It is very hard to take a complex issue down to a "yes" or "no" so I think that they are very hard to do well and in many subjects it is not the right answer. I would say that there are many weaknesses and very few strengths.

  Professor Marsh: One of my colleagues wrote the other day about electoral reform in Ireland and said that if electoral reform is the answer it must be the wrong question and I feel a bit like that with referendums: if referendums are the answer then we are asking the wrong question. I think there are all sorts of apparent strengths of referendums: they involve the people widely, they allow them to have a direct say; they are clearly educative; they move us beyond narrow parties to involve everybody, just as should be done in a democracy. The unfortunate thing is that on the whole it does not do any of those things and quite often it leaves you worse off than you were before. That is probably not to say that there are not times when a referendum seems to be a reasonable safeguard for the people. There were a couple of referendums about changing the electoral system in Ireland which were defeated, and most of us would probably say it was a good thing that they were defeated as well. Most countries do not need referendums to change the electoral system; they do not have parties trying to take very narrow advantage in terms of electoral reform, as we have seen very often in France; and I think if you do have a problem of that sort the solution is not in referendums, you just have big problems which are not solved by referendums. So generally, if your remit states "shall we have referendums or not?", I pass on that one.

  Q158  Lord Norton of Louth: We have dealt with the issue, if you like, of principle, but if we come on then to the practice. If you turn to New Zealand you are in a similar situation to us in that there is no codified constitution so you have the problem of what triggers a referendum. The actual practice, if you could explain what the process is, what is the role of the Electoral Commission, and, from your point of view, what do you see as the benefits and the problems associated with the actual practice?

  Dr Catt: There are three separate sorts of referenda in effect in New Zealand and they all have different triggers and different rules. The Citizens' Initiated Referenda is triggered by a petition from parliament but is non-binding, and is probably the best example of how not to run referenda in the world. The Electoral Commission has no role whatsoever in relation to Citizens' Initiated Referenda. The Chief Electoral Office that runs the elections, as opposed to the Electoral Commission that does education and finance control, actually does the campaign expense component to Citizens' Initiated Referenda, and the legislation there is also not one to be copied. Basically the Citizens' Initiated Referenda and legislation is problematic in every single respect. I would say that I do not think there is a single part of that legislation that works well. All other referenda are initiated by government and there is a new piece of legislation for each one, we do not have any standing legislation about how referenda are run. Each time there is a referendum they pass a piece of legislation and set out the rules for that referendum. So they have been different; the different government-initiated ones have had different rules around them as to whether they are binding or not, as to whether there is a government-funded education campaign, as to what role any other body has. A referendum is being proposed by the current government on the electoral system and they are going to set up an independent panel to run the education campaign; they are not going to give that role to the electoral administration bodies. That was what happened in 1992-93 with the last votes on the electoral system. I would say that whilst Citizens' Initiated Referenda are an example of how not to do it, the referenda in 1992 and 1993 are probably an example of how to do it; that if you really do want to have a referendum, that one was done well mostly because it had a year-long, very well-funded, independently-run education campaign that went with it. I think that is what makes the difference and it is expensive. The regulation is ad hoc really and depends a lot on what question it is and the views of parliament at that time.

  Q159  Lord Norton of Louth: You mentioned earlier that it depends on what the question is. Who actually decides the question?

  Dr Catt: Parliament.

  Q160  Lord Norton of Louth: Do you have any role in commenting on that? Is there any independent body that does?

  Dr Catt: On the Citizens' Initiated Referenda the Clerk of the House is meant to coach the people putting it up as to how to write it well, but the problem has been that most of the people putting up questions have been quite insistent that their question is correct even when it does not meet any of the guidelines, and the Clerk has no power to make them change it. For every other one nobody has a right of comment, but in New Zealand any member of the public can make a submission to the committee that considers a piece of legislation. The only comment on how the question is written would be through that open submission process; but nobody has a right, so it is decided by Parliament in effect.

  Q161  Lord Norton of Louth: And really from what you are saying there are no generic rules?

  Dr Catt: No.

  Q162  Lord Norton of Louth: It is distinct to each?

  Dr Catt: Even though there have been quite a few there is nothing that would be deemed to be tradition or norms, except possibly that they are probably doing the Independent Committee for Education on this upcoming MMP referendum because they did it on the last one, in 1992 and 1993. It is kind of, "It worked last time", so it looks like they have just blown the dust off the briefing papers from last time and brought them forward again. No, there is no generic and no tradition.

  Professor Marsh: There are certainly things to learn from the Irish experience of referendums. I notice my colleagues were described as being "fairly positive" about the referendum experience in Ireland, and they certainly did say that, but I think the subtext in there is how on earth did they come to that conclusion because much of what they say is fairly negative. In terms of the rules governing referendums, referendums are necessary in Ireland to change the constitution and all the referendums we have there are to change the constitution. Sometimes it is because politicians decide they want to change the constitution and sometimes it is the courts that say you need a referendum; for instance, to adopt the Single European Act you need a constitutional change. In at least one case politicians were persuaded by interest groups that they needed to change the constitution and that was probably the worst case of all. In terms of running referendums, originally nothing was done at all. I think that referendum rules tend to follow rules for elections and since we really did not have any expenditure or campaigning rules for elections we did not have any for referendums. They develop slowly, as many things do, by reference to the courts and also by reference to the experience of referendums. So originally the Government would campaign for its own referendum and other people would do their best to campaign against it if necessary. That was taken to court and the court said that it is inappropriate for the Government to spend taxpayers' money putting its own point of view. It seems perfectly reasonable to me in many cases. The Government spends its own money passing its own legislation and some kind of legislation is defined as constitutional and therefore it cannot spend its own money. I do not really accept that, but that is the general view. So a Referendum Commission was then set up and the Referendum Commission was one of the more ludicrous bodies. It was responsible for putting forward the case for and against. Everybody made submissions to this learned body, chaired by a High Court judge, as they always are, and they bought lots of television advertisements and you would have actors saying, "I think we should sign the Treaty of Nice because it is a really good idea because it will ... " Then somebody else would say, "But I am very concerned ... " And it was: "who are these people?" That was responsible for both informing people and giving them the views for and against. I apologise to all the learned judges here, but I think that only people soaked in the law could come up with a view that that was the way to educate the public. The final upshot of that was the total failure of the Treaty of Nice both to get any turnout and to get any support. Then they thought, "Maybe that is not a good idea and we need the Referendum Commission to inform people but we really have to leave it to the public and parties to actually move themselves and get out to argue for what they believe in." So we moved to that situation and that has been the case since. The other change we had was about access to the media and it is really laid down that access to the media really has to be equal for both sides—at least fair for both sides. What does "fair" mean? Before the last referendum on Lisbon the Broadcasting Commission said that fair does not necessarily mean equal; it is not a matter of having a stopwatch and it is not a matter of having someone to say "no" every time you say "yes", it is a little bit more flexible than that. These things are, I suppose, continually under review. Even with the same system you can get different results. For the first Treaty of Lisbon, without running ahead of myself, the Commission was headed by a High Court judge who prepared a document of about 20 pages to explain to everybody what the Treaty of Lisbon was about and most people arrived at the vote not knowing anything about it and, perhaps accordingly, voted "no". The next time around there was a different High Court judge. Now this one was actually very good, and it was a much shorter document and he went on radio regularly on Fridays and dealt with all the things that had been raised and said, "No, that is wrong; that is right," and he was pretty active and a very clear communicator; so he did a very good job and in part was responsible—in a small part—for the change in the vote. In terms of the rules governing how they work, we are still making those up as we go along.

  Q163  Lord Pannick: What is your ideal system, if there is one, for the provision of information to the public on this? Should government have any role at all?

  Professor Marsh: The key thing that people need to know in an argument about a referendum question is, "Who is telling me this?" It is the basic question: "Why is this person lying to me?" You want to know. It is fair enough, I think, to have the Commission to propose some sort of document, but generally I think it is really important that when somebody puts up a poster you know who it is and when somebody is campaigning you know what they are campaigning on behalf of. The more transparency you have of funding the better and that, I think, would be the thing I would be most concerned about—not equal access time or necessarily funding equally, but that you know who is spending whose money trying to persuade me to vote "yes" or "no", because if I do not know that then it is hard to be able to assess it. There is a lot of experimental and other evidence on how people make up their minds when they vote on all sorts of things. We know that people do not make up their minds by judiciously considering all the issues and coming to a well-reasoned, rational conclusion, they tend to go on instinct, on what people call short cuts, and one of the short cuts might be: "Is the CIA funding this?"—"No". Whatever they say—"No".

  Q164  Baroness Quin: Professor Marsh, following up about the Irish experience, given that there are obviously a lot of concerns about how referendums work is there any move afoot to try and limit the use of referendums or, given that that would just be seen as denying the public a voice, is it just impossible to put referendums back in the box once they are out of the box?

  Professor Marsh: No, it is not impossible but the only way to not have referendums would be to have a referendum on not having referendums.

  Q165  Baroness Quin: Do you have any views as to whether that might ever happen?

  Professor Marsh: It might, but it seems unlikely that people would say, "That is great; we will give it up!" Under the first Irish Constitution we actually had Citizens' Initiatives as well and that got quietly buried by Mr de Valera in that debate the second time around in the 1937 Constitution. I think many people feel that at times it is beyond a joke. There is a difficulty in a written constitution that requires a referendum to change it. For instance, the language of the referendum is sexist so it would be nice if it talked about men or women instead of men all the time, or that it used even more mutual language. It would take an awful lot of referendums to change. You either change every clause with a separate referendum or you have a whole new constitution with a referendum to adopt that—that is probably the best way to go, to say: "There are all sorts of things wrong with this constitution, we need a new one; we can clear up all sorts of tidying things and maybe we will limit referendums as a part of that", but I think that in the foreseeable future there is no possibility whatever that the public would put up with that because they would just assume that this was some cunning ploy by politicians again.

  Q166  Lord Wallace of Tankerness: This seems the appropriate time to ask, because you have mentioned the Lisbon Treaty referendums, Professor Butler expressed the first time around, in the first Lisbon Referendum, about how a "leading, flamboyant, rich man charged in and moved opinion really quite substantially"; although the second time he, "crashed in ... and had no impact at all." Could you just comment on that and whether such interventions can be prevented, should they be prevented and has there been any New Zealand experience of one big financier, perhaps one organisation which has been able to put in substantial resources and how do we deal with that?

  Professor Marsh: It is certainly true that Declan Ganley, the very rich businessman, had a big impact the first time and maybe he had a big impact because the politicians had gone missing, the government had its own problems, so there was a vacuum and he stepped into it and he had the money to step into it. It is almost certain that the "no" side outspent the "yes" side. That is the only time they have ever done that. And why should they not do that? Next time round the "yes" side outspent the "no" side and won; so if it was wrong the first time it was wrong the second time. He did a very good job the first time; he argued very well. I would not blame him, I would blame the complete failure of the "no" side to mount any kind of copious campaign. It seems to me very difficult, even if you wanted to do so, to prevent third parties from having a role in referendum campaigns. That is one of the arguments to have referendums, to move in outside parties, to bring in the people more widely. Some people just have more money than others and that is the nature of our society, both here and there. So it seems to me that all you can do is to try and look for some kind of transparency and a lot of the argument about Ganley was, "Where is his money coming from? Is it his money? He has all these shady links", it was said, "with the American armaments industry and we know that they do not like the EU, so is he just a voice for them?" This goes back to the transparency argument I made before that people want to know where the money is coming from. In the first referendum I think that people accepted him at face value; in the second referendum he was much damaged really by his failure to win a seat in the European election, and by other activities.

  Dr Catt: In the 1993 referendum in New Zealand there were a number of businessmen who heavily funded a "no" campaign, which they then lost; so the side with the most money lost, which is very, very unusual in referenda. One of the few stats that are known quite clearly about referenda is that the vast majority of the time the side spending the most money wins; so New Zealand 1993 is one of the few examples when that was not the case. I think you do need spending caps in referenda campaigns of some kind so that people cannot come in with excessive amounts of money, whatever the cap is decided it should be. Transparency is necessary as well in that kind of financing. I think one of the important things in the New Zealand case was that there was this independent government-funded education campaign alongside the "vote this way—vote that way" campaign, so there was the actual information as well as the arguments for both sides, and most of the political parties were also campaigning—mostly against a change in the electoral system as well. So there was a lot of other campaigning going on as well, but, yes, big money went in there.

  Q167  Lord Lyell of Markyate: Looking around the world, what assessment would you make of other nations' experience of referendums? Are there any cases that the Committee should consider as good examples of the use of referendums? I think you have already indicated that there are plenty of bad examples, but are there any of good examples?

  Dr Catt: No, I do not think so. There are really good examples of bad ones. I think the Australian one and the republic is a fantastic example of how to ask the question to get the answer you want, in that the majority of Australians, as far as the polls said, wanted a republic; but from the way that the question was worded and the particular option given to them a lot of people who wanted a republic did not want that form of it. I think that the referenda in both British Columbia and Ottawa on changing the electoral system are a really good example of if you do not do a good informational campaign and you do not give voters time to think about it then it is not going to work well. So those are really good bad examples, but I cannot think of any really good examples.

  Professor Marsh: Broadly I would go along with that, following the comments I made earlier. I do think that it is reasonable to have referendums to set the very narrow rules of the game, perhaps on the electoral system, but if you have them on the electoral system you certainly do need a very long time to explain to people what it is, even when it seems quite simple, as it did in Ireland, and do we want the current system, which people understood, or do we want first past the post, which it does not take a rocket scientist to understand. That seemed simple enough but even that was much more complicated than it seemed. There have been referendums elsewhere on that; there have been referendums on things like the voting age, although why you need a referendum on the voting age I do not know. The Swedes, for instance, had three referendums on the voting age: the first was, "Do we drop it from 21 to 18?" and a huge majority said "no". About five years later, "Shall we drop it from 21 to 20?" and a small majority and a lower turnout said "yes". Then five years later they said, "Shall we drop it from 20 to 18?" There was a lower turnout again and a smaller majority again said yes; so they finished up with it. I think that sort of exercise has much to commend it. The other one, I suppose, where you might argue that they are useful is on basic issues of nationality—"Which country should we be governed by?"—and there are times when one can see that that provides legitimacy to particular political decisions. The Good Friday Agreement referendum in Northern Ireland and in the Republic, in the Republic I think it was relatively trivial but in Northern Ireland it was quite important to get the majority, although there is still some doubt about whether it was a majority of Unionists for that, which I do think helped legitimise the views on peacekeeping. But elsewhere it is the bad things that tend to spring to mind rather than the good ones.

  Q168  Lord Woolf: I think in many ways, Professor Marsh, you have already answered this but perhaps I should just give Dr Catt an opportunity to do so. Assuming that there is going to be a referendum do you have any principles that should be applied to the information that the electorate is given?

  Dr Catt: I think after you write the question the information that voters are given is the most important component of running a good referendum. I think that voters need simple, easy to understand information, on what the different options are provided by an independent body, using good communication methods.

  Q169  Lord Woolf: Such as?

  Dr Catt: Delivered in a variety of ways. I think one of the reasons that the New Zealand one worked is partly it lasted a year. People do not go around thinking about electoral systems all the time; they need to start thinking about it. Although we had first-past-the-post it soon became apparent that a lot of voters did not actually understand first-past-the-post. They thought they were electing the government and they were not, they were electing their local MPs. So there was a lot of misunderstanding about even first-past-the-post. There had to be education about that and for a different alternative to the electoral system. So there were five electoral systems being explained. A lot of it was "Keep it simple" and the booklet that the information campaign had in the end had one page for the basics of each system. It was done graphically and also there were good TV ads done, there were radio debates, there were TV debates, there were lots of people who went out and did talks to Rotary, Women's Institutes, church groups, all the local community groups. People went out and talked to them so that there was a lot of information provided in a lot of ways.

  Q170  Lord Woolf: That was presumably by the Government and the two parties? When I say "the Government", an independent body and by the two parties?

  Dr Catt: All of that information was the independent body, and then there were also interest groups campaigning for the status quo and for MMP, which is the option we have at the moment. A lot of politicians actually kept quiet because most of the politicians were opposed to change, but it became very clear very early on that every time a politician said, "We do not want change" another 2,000 voters decided they would vote for change. So mostly the politicians kept quiet after a while because they were seen as "If they think it is good it must be bad". There was that kind of view going on in New Zealand politics at the time, so actually a lot of the politicians kept quite quiet. There was division inside the major parties as well; there were members of both of the major parties for change and against change, so it was not as if there was a united political party view from the major parties. Mostly it was the independent body—and it truly was an independent campaign—and then the different pressure groups that were doing the campaign and talking about it and stuff.

  Q171  Lord Woolf: Professor Marsh, would you like to add something to that?

  Professor Marsh: No, I have probably made all the points I want to make about education. I spoke to the parallel Committee to this one—a little bit broader and in both chambers—our Committee on the Constitution about referendums about a year ago and there were a couple of points I made that may bear repeating. One is that if you want to set up a Referendum Commission to inform people why do you pick a judge, why do you not pick a tabloid newspaper editor to do it? Or somebody whose expertise lies in communication? I think that needs to be thought about. The other point I wanted to make will come back to me in a minute, but it has just disappeared!

  Q172  Lord Pannick: Do you have any views on the role of the United Kingdom Electoral Commission under the statutes or any views on the performance of our Electoral Commission in relation to referendums?

  Dr Catt: I think that somebody has to oversee regulation of spending and the Electoral Commission seem to be the sensible people to do that—they are doing it anyway. Somebody has to provide an independent education campaign and we feel that the Commission has good experience in that as well. I would be quite happy to see them taking on both of those roles as long as their independence in running the education campaign is guaranteed and there is no government interference in how the education campaign is run.

  Professor Marsh: I would go along with that. I think it is recognition of the need for some kind of regulation and quite a lot of regulation about transparency, some of which we simply do not have in Ireland at the moment, and I think that is useful to be built on. Obviously it has not worked in a lot of referendums yet so we need a bit more experience, and as a political scientist I guess I ought to know more before I talk about it.

  Q173  Lord Rodgers of Quarry Bank: Would you say something further about multi-option referendums? I am not quite clear in my mind how it would look and what the design would be, if I may put it this way. At the moment, as you know, there is a great deal of discussion about whether the Prime Minister is proposing a referendum on what is called "fair voting" which means less unfair voting. I think that the two alternatives to the present voting system might be the AV system and the other is the STV system. On the face of it, it would be quite sensible, if we want to get a clear decision of what the public have in mind, to put those two propositions on the ballot paper. Could you say a word or two about how best to design it and how effective it would be to make sure of maximum vote and a fair choice?

  Dr Catt: The 1992 referendum in New Zealand did have such a question. It actually had two questions. The first was: "Do you want the status quo or do you want to change the electoral system?"—two options. Then the second question was: "If the system is going to be changed which of the four following options would you prefer?", and you only got one tick so you could only choose one. As it happened one system, MMP, the one we have now, won way ahead of everything else, mostly because it was the system that had been recommended by the Royal Commission that had investigated the question of which electoral system should New Zealand have. So it had some history and it was the only one that any pressure groups were arguing for; nobody was arguing for the other three options. It was an unusual campaign and, therefore, it turned out okay because it was way ahead. If the situation had been different and two of the systems had been very close then I do not think the next stage in the process would have had the same legitimacy. I think that there is a real legitimacy issue if you are putting up several options: who is the winner? You might want to use a preferential voting system to choose the options but then it is harder if the argument is about do we want a preferential system in elections. It might be seen as skewing the argument if you then use a preferential system in the referendum. By and large I would say avoid multi-option referenda when you can. To be slightly frivolous, the Australian example of choosing their National Anthem is a really good example of multiple choice referenda, giving everyone a result with which nobody was particularly happy. They had four options and the anthem they have now, which was not the most exciting of the ones that was on offer to them, came through the middle because people were polarised as to the other options. It is one of the few other examples of where multi options were used. So it is fraught, particularly if there is a good chance that two of the options will get quite a close result.

Chairman: Was that Advance Australia Fair? A final question from Lord Hart.

  Q174  Lord Hart of Chilton: You have mentioned funding of referendums and I think from what you have said it emerges that you are in favour of the body regulating funding and the rule is that there should be clarity, fairness and transparency. Are there any other principles that you think should guide it? Dr Catt, in New Zealand there has been capping—and you mentioned capping—could you tell us a little about how capping works?

  Dr Catt: Capping for the Citizens' Initiated Referenda. It is actually quite problematic. The pro side and the anti side are both capped. One of the problems is that the cap is ridiculously low, so it means in effect there is no campaigning it is so low. The other really big problem is that there is often more than one group on each side, but the cap says that there is this amount of money for the pro side—all of them—and this much for the anti side. So who has to choose? Who are the pro side and the anti side? In terms of administering it, it is good that it is so low because in effect nobody really does anything, so it takes the issue away, but in the legislation that they will bring in for the referendum on changing the electoral system this is one of the things that they are really going to have to grapple with. Are you going to let as many groups as you like do it and then how do you stop one rich group setting up ten splinter groups so that they can get round the cap? Regulating finance in elections is always fraught and people will always try and get round the letter of the law; but I still think in principle that there should be a cap on how much can be spent. It is a minefield trying to regulate it.

  Professor Marsh: I think that the transparency and the accountability is the good thing. In an ideal world caps would be nice to ensure greater fairness, but I just think that the difficulties of dealing with that are too great and, to some degree, run counter to the purpose of having referendums, or at least to some of the apparently good things about having referendums, to bring in people in the first place. Just one other point, if I may—it flew back into my head—about information. I was talking to one of our Deputies about the poor information in Lisbon 1 given to people and he complained that when he knocked on a door and said, "I have come to talk about the Lisbon referendum" people would say, "I do not want to know" and shut the door. This is one of the difficulties in informing people about referendums; they do not necessarily want to know, they have other much more important things on their mind—"Big Brother is just on the television; go away, I do not want to know." It does not fit too well with some of our notions about democratic theory but I think it is like youth is wasted on the young, democracy is sometimes wasted on the people.

Chairman: On that note, Dr Catt and Professor Marsh, thank you very much indeed for joining the Committee and for the evidence you have given.


 
previous page contents next page

House of Lords home page Parliament home page House of Commons home page search page enquiries index

© Parliamentary copyright 2010